Born like China, growing like China

Date01 May 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12258
Published date01 May 2019
AuthorXianjuan Chen
ORIGINAL MANUSCRIPT
Born like China, growing like China
Xianjuan Chen
School of Economics, Sichuan University,
Chengdu, China
Correspondence
Xianjuan Chen, School of Economics, Sichuan
University, 24 S 1st Section, 1st Ring Road
Wuhou, Chengdu, Sichuan 610065, China.
Email: zoeychen@scu.edu.cn
Abstract
This paper studies the effects of Chinas one-child policy
on saving and foreign reserve accumulation. Fertility con-
trol increases the saving rate both by altering saving deci-
sions at the household level, and by altering the
demographic composition of the population at the aggre-
gate level. I show that demographically induced changes
in saving explain the build-up of a large foreign surplus in
China. As in Song, Storesletten, and Zilibtti (2011), the
model features contractual and financial market imperfec-
tions. Government-owned firms are less productive but
have full access to the credit market. Entrepreneurial firms
are more productive but face credit constraints. As labour
switches from less productive to more productive firms,
demand for domestic bank borrowing decreases. As saving
increases while demand for loans decreases, domestic sav-
ings are invested abroad, generating a foreign surplus. The
model predicts that Chinas foreign reserve accumulation
will soon begin to slow down in response to recent relaxa-
tion of the one-child policy.
1|INTRODUCTION
In 1979 China introduced the so-called one-child policy, in an effort to reduce population growth
and improve economic conditions. This paper studies the effects of this policy on saving, investment
and foreign reserve accumulation. It constructs a dynamic overlapping generations model, calibrated
to match the unique demographic features of the Chinese experience. Echoing the results of Song,
Storesletten, and Zilibtti (2011), the model shows that Chinas recent current account surpluses may
have nothing to do with exchange rate manipulation, but instead reflect the unique internal charac-
teristics of the Chinese economy. Unlike Song et al., however, I am able to explain the rapid rise in
Chinas saving rate without appealing to exogenous changes in financial market regulations. Instead,
I show that it can be entirely explained by the one-child policy.
Chinas household saving rate has been increasing at a rapid rate. The average urban household
saving rate rose steadily from 12.0% in the early 1980s to approximately 30% in 2010. The one-
child policy influenced saving at both aggregate and household levels. On the one hand, it shifted
Received: 26 January 2017 Revised: 25 July 2017 Accepted: 23 January 2018
DOI: 10.1111/1468-0106.12258
Pac Econ Rev. 2019;24:325347. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/paer © 2018 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd 325
Chinas demographic composition, which influences the aggregate savings rate, even if household sav-
ing rates remain unchanged. At the same time, however, the one-child policy also impacted saving at
the household level. In countries like China, where the social pension system is not well established,
within-family intergenerational transfers are very important. Parents raise and educate their children
when they are young, and children financially support their parents when they retire. Intergenerational
transfers are not just based on cultural norms but are also stipulated by constitutionallaw. Children pro-
vide a crucial source of old age support in China. Thus, when exogenous fertility control is implemen-
ted, householdsconsumption and savingdecisions will be influenced. In addition to explainingChinas
saving puzzle, the one-child policy canalso explain Chinasallocation puzzle. Over the past couple
of decades, China has been experiencing rapid economic growth, sustained capital accumulation and a
growing foreign surplus. This combination is puzzling from the perspective of neoclassical growth the-
ory, which predicts that capital should flow from rich countries to poor countries. Based on this theory,
we should expect to see capital flow into China, given its rapid growth and poor initial economic condi-
tions (Lucas, 1990). Allowing for productivity differences across countries does not help to explain the
puzzle. If productivity levels are converging across countries, then the theory predicts that countries
experiencing relatively rapid convergence should be net international borrowers. The data indicate pre-
cisely the opposite (Gourinchas & Jeanne, 2013). In addition, Jeanne and Rancière (2011) and Bac-
chetta, Benhima, and Kalantzis (2013) found that neither the precautionary motive against aggregate
shocks nor the presence of idiosyncratic shocks can explaininternational reserve accumulation in China.
Wang, Weh, and Xu (2015) point to a two way capital flow puzzle: fixed capital flows from rich
to poor countries, whereas financial capital flows in the opposite direction. They augment a neoclassi-
cal growth model with two wedges: one that distorts firmsinvestment decisions and another that dis-
torts householdssaving decisions. In this paper, I focus only on financial capital. I explain the puzzle
through investment and saving channels as well, but in a different setup. In the model of Wang
et al. (2015), the distortions on both the firm and household sides come from the borrowing con-
straints they are facing. They argue that severe financial frictions in poor countries create a price dif-
ference between the MPK and the real interest rate, both within and across countries. This gap in asset
returns drives the observed two-way capital flows. In contrast, the present paper argues that the puzzle
can be explained solely by internal economic adjustments. On the saving side, household savings
decisions are affected by fertility control, because parents shift their investment in the form of children
towards financial assets. However, in the model of Wang et al. (2015), a borrowing constraint and
exogenous preference shocks induce precautionary saving. Thus, the precautionary saving leads to
excessive household saving. Therefore, in this paper, I endogenize the observed change in household
saving. On the investment side, the borrowing constraint leads to resource reallocation within the
country, which decreases the demand for domestic loans. Because domestic saving increases while
demand for loans decreases, the excess savings flow abroad. Therefore, the present paper is also able
to explain the timing of foreign reserve accumulation.
In this paper, I show that demographically-induced changes in saving can explain the build-up
of a large foreign surplus in China. I borrow one key element from the model of Song et al. (2011).
Their model features financial and contractual imperfections that affect different types of firms
asymmetrically. There are two types of firms in their model, domestic private enterprises (DPE) and
state-owned enterprises (SOE). SOE are less productive but have better access to credit. DPE must
finance their investment through internal savings. I use this idea in my model to explain changes in
the domestic demand for loans. As capital in the DPE sector accumulates, labour switches from the
lower productivity SOE sector to the higher productivity DPE sector. As investment in the finan-
cially integrated SOE sector shrinks, demand for domestic bank borrowing decreases. Domestic sav-
ings are invested abroad, generating a foreign surplus.
326 CHEN

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT