Asymmetric effects of financial development on export price and quality across countries

Published date01 May 2019
AuthorByeongHwa Choi,Volodymyr Lugovskyy
Date01 May 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12390
594
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:594–642.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
A large body of literature has emphasized the importance of financial development (FD) for economic
growth and exporting.1 Nonetheless, recent empirical findings have shown that FD does not affect the
growth of low‐income countries.2 These findings raise questions about how FD affects exporting, and
whether FD benefits all exporting countries equally.
These aforementioned questions motivate us to explore the effects of FD on two essential compo-
nents of exporting: export prices and export quality.3 We find that these effects are highly asymmetric
across countries, and we provide an explanation for these asymmetries. Additionally, our findings
suggest that improving the quality of financial institutions alone is unlikely to boost quality or lower
export prices in low‐income countries.
Theoretically, we provide a unifying framework to explain why and how the effects of FD on
export quality and prices differ across countries. A key component of our model is based on the
Received: 10 May 2018
|
Revised: 18 December 2018
|
Accepted: 19 December 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12390
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Asymmetric effects of financial development on
export price and quality across countries
ByeongHwaChoi1
|
VolodymyrLugovskyy2
1Department of Economics,National Taiwan
University, Taipei, Taiwan (R.O.C.)
2Department of Economics,Indiana
University, Bloomington, Indiana
Correspondence
Volodymyr Lugovskyy, Department
of Economics, Indiana University, 105
Wylie Hall, 100 S. Woodlawn Avenue,
Bloomington, IN 47405.
Email: vlugovsk@indiana.edu
Funding information
The Ministry of Science and Technology of
Taiwan, Grant/Award Number: MOST
106-2410-H-002-001
Abstract
We derive two novel predictions: financial development
has a more pronounced effect on quality in countries with
greater labor productivity, and its effect on export prices is
U‐shaped in labor productivity. We confirm our predic-
tions empirically and show that the negative effect of fi-
nancial development on export prices is greatest in
middle‐productivity countries, while its positive effect on
quality is strongest in the most productive countries. Our
findings contribute to the literature on the poverty trap: we
argue that improving the quality of financial institutions
alone is unlikely to boost quality or lower prices of the
poorest countries.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F10, F14, G20, J24, O14
|
595
CHOI and LUGOVSKYY
complementarities between different inputs—capital, labor productivity, and entrepreneurial talent—
in the production function of quality. Building on Verhoogen (2008), we employ a discrete choice
model, where the production function of quality contains the elements of O‐ring technology (Kremer,
1993). We extend it in two important dimensions: first, we introduce the liquidity constraints of ex-
porting firms in the model and assume that the cost of borrowing decreases in FD.4 Second, in line
with the labor search literature,5 we assume a positive correlation between labor productivity and
entrepreneurial talent across countries.
The model provides three testable predictions: (i) controlling for quality, better FD decreases ex-
port prices; (ii) FD has a positive effect on export quality, and more so in countries with higher labor
productivity, and (iii) for sufficiently large parameter regulating the share of capital in the production
function, the effect of FD on export prices is U‐shaped in labor productivity.
The first effect is the most straightforward: given the same set of inputs, a lower cost of borrowing
reduces the total cost and sequentially the price. The second effect is due to the super‐modularity
of the production function of quality in inputs. As a result, any reduction in the variable produc-
tion cost—including lower borrowing costs owing to better developed financial institutions—induces
firms to upgrade quality.6 Finally, the U‐shaped FD–price pattern emerges from the O‐ring technology
feature of the production function. Specifically, the production of quality requires a firm to pay a stan-
dard wage in a given economy plus a wage premium required to hire better workers to produce higher
quality. While the standard wage portion of the cost is independent of quality, the wage premium and
the amount of capital employed increase in quality. Thus, FD has a negative effect on the quality‐inde-
pendent portion and a positive effect on the quality‐dependent portion of the cost. The magnitude of
the latter effect is determined by the level of labor productivity, which produces a U‐shaped pattern.
Empirically, we test our predictions using product‐level U.S. Census Imports Data over the span of
17 years (1991–2007). We focus on differentiated goods, which are more likely to be subject to quality
differentiation. The FD is proxied by the private credit‐to‐GDP ratio, and its effect on export prices
tends to be negative but non‐uniform across exporting countries. Specifically, the effect is strongest
for countries where real GDP per worker is around U.S.$22,000: for these countries, the price de-
creases by 1.87% for every 10 percentage point increase in the private credit‐to‐GDP ratio. The effect
is much weaker for all other countries, whether wealthier or poorer. This confirms the predicted U‐
shaped relationship between the effect of FD on export prices and labor productivity. As predicted,
controlling for quality, FD has a negative effect on export prices.
To evaluate the effect of FD on export quality, we use average country‐product quality indices of
exporting goods estimated by Feenstra and Romalis (2014). We find only a partial support for our
second prediction: the effect of FD on quality increases in labor productivity, but it is positive only
after a threshold of U.S.$17,700 for per‐worker productivity.
We perform several robustness checks: (i) we use less parametric specifications with country group
dummies and their interaction terms with FD; (ii) we use Khandelwal’s (2010) quality measure in-
stead of that of Feenstra and Romalis (2014); (iii) we instrument FD with the La Porta, Lopez‐de
Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998) measures of legal origin; (iv) we use the total factor productivity
(TFP) measure obtained from the Penn World Table instead of real GDP per worker as the labor pro-
ductivity measure; and (v) we split the sample into subsamples based on the value of the elasticity
of substitution and based on the length of Khandelwal’s (2010) quality ladder. We confirm that our
results are robust to these checks.
To summarize, FD affects export determinants differently across countries. It: (i) increases export
quality and only marginally reduces export prices among high‐income countries7; (ii) significantly
reduces prices and has no effect on quality among middle‐income countries; and (iii) marginally re-
duces prices among low‐income countries. These results aid in interpreting our finding that FD does
596
|
CHOI and LUGOVSKYY
not increase exports of low‐income countries, and also help us to distinguish between the quality and
price effects of FD on exports for countries with different income levels.
Our results allow us to conclude that the complementarity in quality production works against
the least‐developed countries: they are unlikely to improve quality and increase exports by simply
improving their financial institutions. This finding contributes to the literature on the poverty trap8
by suggesting that improved access to credit markets alone might not be sufficient for better export
performance.
We further contribute to the literature on export quality and prices by highlighting the interac-
tion between income per worker and FD as export quality and price determinants. Schott (2004) and
Hummels and Klenow (2005), among others, have shown that wealthier countries export higher‐
priced goods.9 They attribute this pattern to quality differentiation. The positive correlation between
product quality and FD is also well‐documented (e.g., Ciani & Bartoli, 2015; Fan, Lai, & Li, 2015).
Additionally, Secchi, Tamagni, and Tomasi (2016) show that firms facing tight credit constraints
charge higher export prices in the presence of both quality and cost adjustment effects. Our novel
findings are that the effects of FD on export quality and prices are nonlinear and vary greatly across
countries. We also predict theoretically and confirm empirically that in some cases, FD decreases ex-
port prices while increasing export quality. These findings contribute to the ongoing debate regarding
the conditions under which price is positively correlated with quality.10
Finally, we extend the growing empirical literature documenting the systematic variation in the
impact of FD on export performance. For instance, Manova (2013) argues that FD increases both the
number of exported products and their export values, particularly in financially vulnerable sectors.
Similarly, Crinò and Ogliari (2017) show that FD raises the average quality and the relative exports
disproportionately more in financially vulnerable sectors. Berthou (2010) finds a hump‐shaped rela-
tionship between the marginal effect of FD on exports and the initial development of financial insti-
tutions in industries where firms have a high demand for external finance. Our paper focuses on the
asymmetry of the effect of FD on exports across countries, rather than across sectors, while all time‐
varying product‐specific factors are captured by a set of product–year fixed effects.11 Importantly,
we show that the effects of FD on export prices and quality differ across countries. Thus, the optimal
export‐promoting policies are likely to be country‐specific rather than universal.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 presents the model; Section 3 outlines
the data and empirical strategy; Section 4 discusses the results and robustness checks; and Section 5
concludes.
2
|
MODEL
We build on the endogenous quality choice model of Verhoogen (2008) and adapt it to a multi‐country
setting and liquidity‐constrained firms. Our goal is to explore how FD affects the export quality and
price across countries‐exporters with different levels of labor productivity. We establish our model
from the perspective of a firm in Country d = 1, 2, 3, … ,D, and examine its export quality and price
choices to an importing country, Importer.
We deviate from Verhoogen’s (2008) original model in two ways. First, we simplify the model
by assuming away firm heterogeneity within a country and focusing only on the asymmetry of firms
across countries. Second, motivated by labor search models, we consider that wages and entrepreneur-
ial talent are not exogenously given but are increasing functions of the average labor productivity in
a country.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT