Asset Accumulation in Rural Households during the Post‐Showa Depression Reconstruction: A Panel Data Analysis*

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/asej.12091
AuthorMasanori Takashima,Motoi Kusadokoro,Takeshi Maru
Published date01 June 2016
Date01 June 2016
Asset Accumulation in Rural Households during
the Post-Showa Depression Reconstruction:
A Panel Data Analysis*
Motoi Kusadokoro, Takeshi Maru and Masanori Takashima
Received 25 November 2013; Accepted 9 February 2016
This paper investigates asset accumulation in Japanese farm households during
reconstruction following the Showa Depression. After the ShowaDepression, farm
households emphasized accumulation of cash and quasi-money rather than produc-
tive assets. The accumulation of cash and quasi-money is consistent withthe buffer
stock hypothesis. Evidence regarding accumulation of livestock, which is some-
times used as the buffer stock in modern developing countries, is not conclusive.
The presence of well-developed nancial institutions in prewar Japan may have
allowed farm households to smooth consumption via cash and quasi-money.
Keywords: asset accumulation, buffer stocks, farm households, prewar Japan.
JEL classication codes: N55, O12, Q12.
doi: 10.1111/asej.12091
I. Introduction
Farm households have two main motivations for holding assets. First, assets are
the source of agricultural production, and, hence, income generation, especially
productive assets such as land and livestock. Second, farm households can use
an asset as a buffer stock to smooth consumption by withdrawing the accumulated
assets when faced with negative income shocks. The second motivation is more
relevant in developing economies, where access to formal credit and insurance
markets is limited. This coping strategy may decrease the ability of the household
*Kusadokoro (corresponding author): Institute of Agriculture, Tokyo University of Agriculture and
Technology, 3-5-8 Saiwai-cho, Fuchu, Tokyo 183-8509, Japan. Email: motoi_k@cc.tuat.ac.jp. Maru:
The Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University,2-1 Naka, Kunitachi, Tokyo 186-8603,
Japan. Email: marl@ier.hit-u.ac.jp. Takashima: The Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi
University,2-1 Naka, Kunitachi, Tokyo 186-8603, Japan. Email: takamasa@ier.hit-u.ac.jp. The authors
gratefully acknowledge the nancial support of Grants-in-Aid (#25245047, #22243030, and
#22223003) from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science and the Japanese Ministryof Educa-
tion, Culture, Sports, Science and Technologythrough the Research Unit for Statistical and Empirical
Analysis in Social Sciences Center of Excellence Program. We are grateful to Atsushi Chitose, Takeshi
Fujie, YukinobuKitamura, Takashi Kurosaki, Ken Miura, Tetsuji Okazaki, TakeshiSakurai, and Takao
Yurugi, an anonymous referee, the editors of this journal for their comments and suggestions, and to
Hastoya and Syunsuke Fukumuro for organizing the data.
© 2016 East Asian Economic Association and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
Asian Economic Journal 2016, Vol.30 No. 2, 221246 221
bs_bs_banner
to generate future income if a negative income shock leads to large losses in
productive assets (Dercon, 2004).
Coping strategies against income shocks have been intensively investigated in
modern developing countries. Empirical literature on saving behavior shows that
households in developing economies save a large part of their transitory income
to smooth consumption (Paxson, 1992; Alderman, 1996). However, the ability
to smooth consumption depends on the wealth of the household (Jalan and
Ravallion, 1999), and the precautionary motive for saving is higher in households
with liquidity constraints (Lee and Sawada, 2010).
Livestock has been recognized as an important buffer stock. Rosenzweig and
Wolpin (1993) provide evidence from Indian farmers to support this hypothesis.
On the contrary, some studies on Africa show the reluctance of farm households
to sell livestock under negative income shocks (e.g. Fafchamps et al., 1998;
Kazianga and Udry, 2006). Rather, they compensate the loss of transitory income
by adjusting grain stock (Kazianga and Udry, 2006).
Recent empirical literature considers the dynamic aspects of asset accumula-
tion. When a household has a precautionary motive and utilizes an asset as a
buffer stock, then the asset holding has an equilibrium (target) level (Carroll
and Kimball, 2008). However,asset dynamics have multiple equilibria if a poverty
trap is present in the economy (Carter and Barrett, 2006). Mogues (2011) applies
the dynamic model assuming a single equilibrium on the accumulations of
livestock and grain stock of Ethiopian farmers. Her ndings are consistent with
the buffer stock hypothesis for both assets. Carter and Lybbert (2012) nd a
threshold size of herding in Burkina Faso, in that farm households with herding
below the threshold prefer asset smoothing over consumption smoothing.
Studies investigating asset adjustments against income shocks generally focus
on livestock and grain stock. Most of the investigated areas are characterized by
semi-arid or arid climatic conditions, prevalence of animal husbandry, and lack
of well-developed nancial institutions. The asset dynamics of farm households
under different environments may vary from those of the empirical studies. More-
over, the effects of nancial institutions on asset dynamics are still unclear.
Examining the historical experiences of modern developed countries can help
ll this gap, because the environments surrounding households in the early phase
of economic development in these countries may have differed from those in
modern developing countries, even if their income levels were broadly compara-
ble. James et al. (2007) nd that the saving behaviors of working-class American
families in the late 19th and early 20th centuries are consistent with the precau-
tionary models. Evidence from farm households is still lacking, however, largely
because of data scarcity (Kurosaki, 2013).
The Japanese rural economy in the prewar period (before 1945) provides an
interesting example. Japanese agriculture in those days was characterized by an
abundance of labor, a scarcity of land, and temperate and humid climatic condi-
tions. Agricultural land was the most important productive asset, and animal
husbandry was not so common. Importantly, government interventions helped
ASIAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL 222
© 2016 East Asian Economic Association and John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT