Why Has China's Current Account Balance Converged after the Global Financial Crisis?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/cwe.12367
Date01 January 2021
Published date01 January 2021
©2021 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
China & World Economy / 109–129, Vol. 29, No. 1, 2021 109
*Jianwei Xu, Professor, School of Economics and Business Administration, Beijing Normal University, China. Email:
xujianwei@gmail.com; Panpan Yang (corresponding author), Senior Research Fellow, Institute of World Economics
and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, China. Email: pamelapanda@126.com; Guangrong Ma, Professor,
China Financial Policy Research Center, School of Finance, Renmin University of China, China. Email: grma@ruc.
edu.cn. The authors thank Bin Zhang and other attendees at the Second China–Japan Youth Conference on Trade,
Exchange Rate and Labor and anonymous reviewers for their helpful suggestions. The authors acknowledge f‌i nancial
support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos. 71773125, 71973142, and 71673028) and
Important Projects in the Scientif‌i c Innovation of CASS (Research on the Major Risks of China in the Next 15 Years).
Why Has China’s Current Account Balance
Converged after the Global Financial Crisis?
Jianwei Xu, Panpan Yang, Guangrong Ma*
Abstract
China’s current account surplus declined signif‌i cantly from its peak of nearly 10 percent
of GDP in 2007 to less than 1 percent in 2018. The new pattern offered fresh evidence
for our understanding of China’s current account dynamics. In this paper, we used f‌l ow
of funds data to gauge its underlying driving forces. Specifically, by employing index
decomposition analysis, we decomposed the current account from the perspective of
savings and investment into three sectors: the household, corporate, and government
sectors. We found that the decline in China’s current account ratio was f‌i rst driven by
cyclical factors, i.e. weak corporate saving growth induced by the economic slump in
2009 as well as the following massive corporate investment bolstered by the government
stimulus plan. However, such cyclical factors quickly subsided, and the subsequent
current account balance reduction was later supported by structural factors, i.e.
household savings declined enduringly and the Chinese government switched to a more
expansionary fiscal policy. There are three possible explanations for the structural
movement: reduced precautionary saving due to higher social security coverage ratio,
lower corporate prof‌i ts as a result of economic slowdown, and a twin def‌i cit due to the
government’s more relaxed f‌i scal stance. The new facts, however, were not consistent with
other current account theories focusing on long-term aspects of the savinginvestment
account puzzle, especially those relating to China’s special demographic characteristics.
Key words: current account, f‌l ow of funds accounts, investment, saving
JEL codes: E21, E22, G21
I. Introduction
Debate over China’s current account surplus has often featured in the global news.
However, the once seemingly unstoppably growing current account surplus ended
Jianwei Xu et al. / 109–129, Vol. 29, No. 1, 2021
©2021 Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
110
with the global f‌i nancial crisis and then experienced a drastic reversal, with the current
account surplus share of GDP shrinking signif‌i cantly, from nearly 10 percent in 2007 to
less than 1 percent in 2018. What’s more, according to the IMF 2018 External Sector
Report (IMF, 2018), there could even be a possible current account def‌i cit in the future.
Thus, the question is why and how China’s current account balance embarked on such a
diminishing trajectory over the past 10 years.
The literature trying to explain China’s current account balance can be traced back
to the 2000s when it started to accrue, reaching a peak in 2007. Most of the studies
focused on the particular pattern of China’s high household saving rate, producing
a number of novel theories highlighting special features such as the demographic
transition, precautionary saving, and gender imbalance (Modigliani and Cao, 2004;
Horioka and Wan, 2007; Du and Wei, 2010; Zhou, 2012). Several theories also emerged
focusing on the particularly high corporate saving rate and linking it with China’s
special institutional characteristics (Song et al., 2011). All in all, these explanations
associated China’s increasing current account surplus with structural characteristics of
its economy and fitted them with the intertemporal open macroeconomic framework
(Obstfeld and Rogoff, 1995).
However, most of the evidence used to support the above theories was based on
China’s pre-2007 current account balance movement. There has been a sharp reversal
of the situation ever since then. After the global f‌i nancial crisis, China’s current account
ratio (as a proportion of GDP) slumped from about 9.1 percent in 2008 to less than
1.8 percent in 2011, and then remained at a low level and continued decreasing (Figure 1).
This seemed to cast doubt on the validity of some of the previous theories focusing
on long-term structural factors, such as demographic characteristics, which actually
only experienced a very gradual change after the crisis. Extending the evidence to the
post-2007 period thus offers novel opportunities to reassess the validity of the above
theories.
To account for the new pattern, a few studies examined the recent movement of the
current account balance in China. For example, The Economist (2019a, b) highlighted
that the negative drift in the current account was due to the cyclical shift of the high
prices of Chinese imports, such as oil and semiconductors, and the rising labor cost,
which led to lower exporting capacity. Furthermore, the service trade sector deficit
also offered an important channel that offset a large amount of the goods trade surplus,
contributing to the worse current account def‌i cit following the global f‌i nancial crisis.
That said, to the best of our knowledge, there seemed to be little evidence to revisit the
theories proposed earlier.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT