The welfare effect of a free trade agreement in the presence of foreign direct investment and rules of origin

Date01 September 2017
Published date01 September 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12282
AuthorHiroshi Mukunoki
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The welfare eect of a free trade agreement in the
presence of foreign direct investment and rules of
origin
Hiroshi Mukunoki
Faculty of Economics, Gakushuin
University, Tokyo, Japan
Correspondence
Faculty of Economics, Gakushuin
University, Mejiro 1-5-1, Toshima-ku,
Tokyo 171-8588, Japan;
Tel: 181-3-5992-1275;
Fax: 181-3-5992-1275;
Email: hiroshi.mukunoki@gakushuin.
ac.jp
Funding information
Japanese Society for the Promotion of
Science Grants-in-Aid for Scientic
Research (JSPS KAKENHI) Grant
Numbers 16H03620 and 26380310
JEL Classication: F12, F13, F15
Abstract
This paper investigates the welfare eect of forming a free
trade agreement (FTA). To receive tari-free treatment,
rms must comply with the rules of origin (ROO). Outside
rms could undertake either market-oriented or export-
platform foreign direct investments (FDIs). ROO have the
following eects: (i) An infeasible FTA may become feasi-
ble by deterring outside rmsFDIs, (ii) an FDI of a less
ecient rm could replace that of an ecient rm, or (iii)
FDIs made before the FTA is concluded might be elimi-
nated. These potential eects complicate the welfare eect
of the FTA and could decrease the consumer surplus.
KEYWORDS
free trade agreements, rules of origin, foreign direct invest-
ment, internati onal oligopoly
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Regional trade agreements (RTAs) have increased signicantly worldwide. As of December 2016, 431
RTAs were in eect and reported to the World Trade Organization (WTO) compared with 28 in 1990.
By forming an RTA, member countries reciprocally remove their trade barriers while maintaining such
barriers for nonmember countries. There are two types of RTAs, free trade agreements (FTA) and cus-
toms unions (CU). Each FTA member independently sets external taris on nonmember countries
while CU members jointly set common external taris. Because the external tarisofFTAscandier,
without rules to distinguish between the products originating within an FTA and those originating
from outside an FTA, nonmembers would supply their goods to member countries through the mem-
bers with the lowest tari. To prevent such taricircumvention, rules of origin (ROO) are indispensa-
ble for the implementation of FTAs. ROO require goods to be certicatedasproducedwithinanFTA
only if a substantial transformationoccurred within the FTA.
1
The methods to check the substantial transformation within an FTA are as follows: (i) changes in
tari-classication (CTC) criterion, (ii) value-content (VC) criterion, and (iii) specic-process (SP)
Rev Int Econ. 2017;25:733759. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie V
C2017 JohnWiley & Sons Ltd
|
733
Received: 10 October 2015
|
Revised: 4 October 2016
|
Accepted: 12 December 2016
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12282
criterion.
2
The CTC criterion grants the origin if several imported intermediates of member countries
are transformed into products with a dierent tariclassication. The VC criterion requires producers
to add more than a minimum percentage of value within the FTA. The SP criterion requires that certain
production or processing be conducted within the FTA. Although the CTC criterion is commonly used
in FTAs, the other two methods are frequently combined with the CTC criterion.
To meet ROO, the production of the good basically must use a certain fraction (denoted by gin
this paper) of parts and components that originate within the FTA. The fraction gis explicitly specied
when the ROO is based on a VC criterion. The CTC and the SP criteria do not explicitly require the
local sourcing of parts and intermediates, but rms must practically use a ce rtain fraction of l ocally
sourced parts and intermediates to change the tariclassication of goods produced with imported
inputs and undertake specic processes in local production.
Although the primary purpose of ROO is to prevent taricircumvention, they can have many side
eects. ROO has similar properties to local content requirements (LCRs) imposed on FDI. Both ROO
andLCRsrequiretheinvestingrms to devote a certain amount of local parts or intermediates to local
production and have become an impediment to FDI. An important dierence is that although LCRs
are prohibited under WTO rules, incorporating ROO when forming an FTA is legitimate policy despite
the risk of distorting rmslocation choices as LCRs may. Another important dierence is that inves-
ting rms have an option not to comply with ROO and not to use tari-free access within the FTA, but
they are obliged to meet the content rule in the case of LCRs.
The main focus of this paper is to examine the ways in which the formation of an FTA changes the
pattern of foreign direct investments (FDIs) made by non-FTA country rms and the ways in which
the changes are connected to the restrictiveness of the ROO. Because FTAs build free trade zones
among member countries, establishing a plant in one member country gives the investing rm an
opportunity to make t ari-free exports to other member countries. Therefore, the formation of an FTA
attracts FDI from an outside country to a member country. This type of FDI is referred to as a third-
country export- platform FDI(P-FDI hereafter).
3
Some empirical studies showed that FTAs promote FDIs from outside countries. For instance,
Blomstr
om and Kokko (1997) found that the U.S.Canada FTA increased FDIs into Canada, and the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) promoted FDIs into Mexico. With a large sample of
countries, Levy-Yeyati, Stein, and Daude (2003) explored the positive eect of RTAs on FDIs from
outside countries. These FDIs should include P-FDIs. For instance, Ito (2013a) pointed out that the
third-country exports of U.S. FDI are signicantly larger for the plants operated in the Association of
South-East Asian Nations (ASEAN). Ito (2013b) obtained the same result for Japanese plants operated
in ASEAN and NAFTA. There is also anecdotal evidence that FTAs promote P-FDIs. It is reported
that Sumitomo Chemical Co. Ltd., a Japanese chemical company, established a new plant in Korea for
exporting its products to the United States by utilizing the U.S.Korea FTA.
4
After the formation of
the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA), a German automaker, BMW, newly established a plant in Thai-
land and has been supplying cars in Thailand and also exporting them to Indonesia.
5
Because rms must meet the requirements of the ROO to enjoy tari-free exports within FTAs,
ROO is associated with outside rmsgains from P-FDI. Specically, stricter ROO increase the cost of
obtaining a certicate of FTA originand reduces outside rmsincentive to undertake P-FDI. Este-
vadeordal, L
opez-C
ordova, and Suominen (2006) reported that FDI into Mexico after the implementa-
tion of NAFTA has owed in sectors with less stringent ROOs.
However, if the aim of undertaking an FDI is to serve the local market of the host country, which
is referred to as a market-oriented FDI(M-FDI hereafter), ROO has no eect because rms need not
comply with ROO. Therefore, ROO only raises the cost of undertaking P-FDI and does not aect the
cost of undertaking M-FDIs. For instance, Honda Motor Co. Ltd. has plants in both the United States
734
|
MUKUNOKI

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT