The Footloose Entrepreneur model with a finite number of equidistant regions

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12215
Date01 December 2020
AuthorJosé M. Gaspar,Sofia B.S.D. Castro,João Correia‐da‐Silva
Published date01 December 2020
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12215
The Footloose Entrepreneur model with a finite number of
equidistant regions
Jos´
eM.Gaspar,Sofia B.S.D. Castroand Jo˜
ao Correia-da-Silva
Westudy the Footloose Entrepreneur model with a finite number of equidistant regions, focusing
on the analysis of stability of agglomeration, total dispersion, and boundary dispersion. As the
number of regions increases, there is more tendency for agglomeration and less tendency for
dispersion. As it tends to infinity, agglomeration always becomes stable while dispersion always
becomes unstable. These results are robust to any composition of the global workforce and its
dependence on the number of regions. Numerical evidence suggests that boundary dispersion is
never stable. Weintroduce exogenous regional heterogeneity and obtain a general condition for
stability of agglomeration.
Key wor ds core-periphery, Footloose Entrepreneur,multiple regions, agglomeration
JEL classification R10, R12, R23
Accepted 22 December 2018
1 Introduction
The secular tendency for spatial agglomeration of economic activity is well known and has always
been a matter of profound debate. Recent developments have allowed a morer igoroustreatment of
such phenomena, with recourse to microeconomic foundations.1The benchmark in this literature is
the Core-Periphery (CP) model, introduced by Krugman (1991). However, several issues have been
raised in the recent literature about possible shortcomings due to some simplifying assumptions.
One of these shortcomings is the prevalent focus on the 2-region framework.
Lisbon Schoolof Economics and Management, University of Lisbon, Lisbon, Católica Porto Business School, Universidade
Católica Portuguesa and CEF.UP, University of Porto, Porto,Portugal. Email: jgaspar@porto.ucp.pt
CMUP and Faculty of Economics, University of Porto,Porto, Portugal.
CEF.UPand Faculty of Economics, University of Porto , Porto, Portugal. Email: jgaspar@porto.ucp.pt
We thank Kristian Behrens, PasqualeCommendatore, Laura Gardini, Paulo Guimar˜
aes, Kiyohiro Ikeda, Ingrid Kubin,
VascoLeite, Pascal Mossay,Minoru Osawa, Cesaltina Pires, Jos ´
e PedroPontes, Irina Sushko, two anonymous referees and
the Associate Editor for very useful comments and suggestions. Wealso thank participants in the 2nd Ph.D. Workshop
on Industrial and Public Economics at Reus, the 3rd Industrial Organization and Spatial Economics conference at
Saint Petersburg, and the International Conference ESCOs 2018 at Naples. This work also benefited from discussions
while Jos´
e Gaspar visited Tohoku University. This research was financed by the European Regional Development Fund
through COMPETE 2020 – Programa Operacional Competitividade e Internacionalização (POCI) and by Portuguese
Public Funds through Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia in the fr amework of projects POCI-01-0145-FEDER-
006890, PEst-OE/EGE/UI4105/2014, PEst-C/MAT/UI0144/2013, PTDC/EGE-ECO/30080/2017, and Ph.D. scholarship
SFRH/BD/90953/2012. Part of this work was developed while Jo˜
ao Correia-da-Silva was a Marie CurieFellow at Toulouse
School of Economics, financed by the EuropeanCommission (H2020-MSCA-IF-2014-657283).
1See Fujita, Krugman, and Venables(1999), Ottaviano, Tabuchi, and Thisse (2002), Baldwin et al. (2004), Robert-Nicoud
(2005) and the references therein.
International Journal of Economic Theory (2019) 1–27 © IAET 1
International Journal of Economic Theory 16 (2020) 420–446 © IAET
420
International Journal of Economic Theory
Multi-region FE model Jos´
e M. Gaspar et al.
Theoretical insights on a model with three or more regions are interesting for different reasons.
One reason is the understanding of interdependenciesamong many regions to guide empirical studies
(Bosker, Brakman, Garretsen, and Schramm 2010). A two-region set-up overlooksthe var iability of
market access across regions (Fujita and Thisse 2009), thus more complex spatial patterns mayarise
in a multi-regional set-up compared to a two-region one (Fujita and Mori 2005; Fujita and Thisse
2009; Behrens and Robert-Nicoud 2011; Akamatsu, Takayama, and Ikeda 2012; Gaspar 2018). As
pointed out byFujita, Krugman, and Venables (1999) and Berliant and Mori (2017), the consideration
of only two regions stems from the advantage of dealing with more tractable problems, although it
seems implausible that the geographical dimension of economic activity can be reduced to a 2-region
framework. It is important, therefore, to understand to what extent the main conclusions obtained
using 2-region models extend to models with more regions.
This has motivated a number of different studies. Castro, Correia-da-Silva, and Mossay (2012)
studied a 3-region version of the CP model by Krugman (1991), and also a version with an even
number of regions equally spaced around a circle. Comparing the 3-region model with the 2-region
model, they concluded that the additional region favors the agglomeration of economic activity and
hinders the dispersion of economic activity.
Akamatsu, Takayama, and Ikeda (2012) and Ikeda, Akamatsu, and Kono (2012) studied agglom-
eration processes in a CP model with 2nequally spaced regions around a circle. They applied the
discrete Fourier transformation to identify eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix of the dynamical sys-
tem as a unimodal function of a spatial discounting matrix which accounts for the spatial patternsdue
to agglomeration and dispersion forces that operate differently in every region. This allowed them
to determine which equilibrium configurations arise after a decrease in transport costs that deems
the symmetric equilibrium unstable. They uncovered a spatial period doubling bifurcation whereby
the number of regions in which firms locate is reduced by half and the spacing between each pair
of adjacent “core” regions doubles after each bifurcation. If consumers are homogeneous regarding
preferences for residential location, the economy may eventually converge to full agglomeration. If
they are heterogeneous, a bifurcation may occur at some late stage that reverts the spatial economy
to the fully symmetric outcome, thus lending support to the idea of a bell-shaped curve of spatial
development in other models with heterogeneous preferences such as Tabuchi and Thisse (2002) and
Murata (2003).
Oyama (2009) incorporated self-fulfilling expectations in migration decisions in a multi-regional
variant of the CP model and studied global stability of agglomeration. He found that a fully symmet-
ric setup deems the choice of forward looking expectations and myopic migration for the dynamics
irrelevant. In this case, initial advantages and history determine the resulting spatial distribution.
With exogenous asymmetries, perfect foresight of migrants originates a unique globally stable equi-
librium corresponding to agglomeration in a region that is either relatively protected (lower trade
barriers) or has the potentially largest market size, irrespective of the initial state.
Tabuchi and Thisse (2011) studied the rise of a hierarchical system of centr al places in a multi-
location space. Barbero and Zof´
ıo (2016) considered different network topologies to study how
the interplay between centripetal and centrifugal forces changes according to the heterogeneity of
location space. They showed that more heterogeneous configurations increase the likelihood of
agglomeration in regions with higher centrality; that is, those that are relatively better located.
The role of heterogeneousdistances between regions has also been addressed in other frameworks,
such as the racetrack economy,with either a discrete or a continuous uniform distribution of locations
(Krugman 1993; Fujita, Krugman, and Venables1999; Picard and Tabuchi 2010; Mossay 2013; Ago,
Hamoudi, and Lefouili 2017), three equally spaced regions locatedon a line (Ago, Isono, and Tabuchi
2006), or hexagonal distributions (Ikeda, Murota, and Takayama 2017a). Ikeda, Murota, Akamatsu,
2International Journal of Economic Theory (2019) 1–27 © IAET
International Journal of Economic Theory 16 (2020) 420–446 © IAET 421

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT