The evolution of the monitoring board in Japan: how the board performs monitoring function in Japanese corporate governance

DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1108/CG-07-2018-0245
Published date07 October 2019
Pages999-1014
Date07 October 2019
AuthorKohei Miyamoto
Subject MatterStrategy,Corporate governance
The evolution of the monitoring board in
Japan: how the board performs
monitoring function in Japanese
corporate governance
Kohei Miyamoto
Abstract
Purpose The purpose of this paper is to trace a legal evolution of the monitoring board and to reveal
what brought the evolution and what is expected to emerge. The paper points to unique
complementarities in Japanese corporate governance institutions and norms which will affect how the
monitoringboard performs its functions.
Design/Methodology/Approach Analysis is based on texts on corporate governance legislations in
Japan from the revision of Commercial Code in 1950 to the revision of Companies Act in 2014. Other
sources include Tokyo Stock Exchange regulations, White Paper on Corporate Governance and other
academicliteratures on Japanese corporategovernance.
Findings Changes of non-legal institutions and norms in Japanese corporate governance
necessitated legal reforms toward the monitoring board. Persisting institutionsand norms, in particular
lifetimeemployment, influences how the monitoringboard performs its functions in Japan.
Originality/Value This paper explains how the evolutionof the monitoring board in Japan emerged
and what will cause different expected functions of the monitoring board in Japan and other
jurisdictions.
Keywords Board of directors, Corporate governance, Legislation
Paper type Research paper
1. Introduction
Whether systems of corporate governance in different economies are converging into a single
model has been the focus of academic research. Hansmann and Kraakman (2001) insisted
that the basic features of company law and corporate governance were converging on a
single American model: ultimate control by shareholders and directors’ duty to pro mote
shareholder interest. They also predicted convergence toward a one-tier board structure w ith
a majority of independent directors. The boards of directors with a majority of independent
directors are expected to monitor executives: the “monitoring board”. The monitoring board,
whichisaninventionofEisenberg (1976), has been developed in American corporate
governance since the 1970s. The prominent feature of the monitoring board is having
independent directors who monitor the management of companies to enhance compani es’
performance. Boards are, in particular, expected to evaluate the performance of the
executives and to appoint and dismiss them so as to improve the performance of companies.
The theory of the monitoring board has inspired the reforms of corporate governance in
Japan. The recent developments ofcompany law, such as introducing Company with Triple
Committees in 2002 and continuing the debate on mandatory appointment of outside/
Kohei Miyamoto is based at
the Faculty of Law, Chuo
University, Hachioji, Japan.
Received 27 July 2018
Revised 17 December 2018
24 February 2019
Accepted 24 March 2019
DOI 10.1108/CG-07-2018-0245 VOL. 19 NO. 5 2019, pp. 999-1014, ©Emerald Publishing Limited, ISSN 1472-0701 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCE jPAGE 999
independent directors, show a shift in policy towards the monitoring board. The shift
appears to show an evidence for the convergence of corporate governance as Hansmann
and Kraakman (2001) predicted. The increasing number of outside/independent directors
could support the evidence regarding thesuccess of transplanting the monitoring board.
However, how the board with outside/independent directors might function in Japanese
corporate governance context remains elusive. The theory of “legal transplants” predicts th at
transplanted legal rules often do not work as in origin countries. They may retain a formal
similarity with the original rules but be different in substance (Cohn, 2010;Siems, 2014).
Therefore, the focus should be on functional analysis. Any attempt to predict how
the monitoring board might function within Japanese corporate governance requires the
considering the whole structure of corporate governance. In particular, the success o f the post
war Japanese economy was supported by complementarities of non-legal institutions and
norms such as stable/cross shareholding, main bank system, lifetime employment and insider-
dominated board. Some of these institution and norms demised; others changed its form while
shrinking. According to the theory of legal transplants, we can predict that board might play
unique functions in Japan.
The purpose of this paper is three fold:
to trace the reception of Eisenberg’s model of the monitoring board in Japan;
to map out the legal changes intended to implement the monitoring board in J apan; and
to identify some of the consequences of these changes for corporate governance in
Japan. It is structured as follows.
Section 2 reviews a number of changes in Japanese company law and evaluates the extent
to which they shift the legal model of the board in the direction of monitoring. It identifies
some of the key macroeconomic drivers of this change. Section 3 then looks at the wider
corporate governance system and the social, cultural and historical factors which influence
the ways in which boards discharge their responsibilities in practice. Section 4 shows how
the company law reforms have interacted with wider factors and will produce boards which
are sui generis, in some ways similar to the US monitoring board, whilst in others, very
different. Some of the implications of these findings for Japanese corporate governance
and the theory of legal transplants are tentativelyidentified in a brief conclusion in Section 5.
2. Changes in corporate governance in Japan
2.1 The monitoring board
The concept of the monitoring board was developed in the USA during 1970s. It was first
invented by Eisenberg (1976) and later accepted by American corporate governance practice.
According to Eisenberg, in the early 1970s, American economy experienced the major downfalls
of some companies such as Penn Central. At that time, company laws in most American
jurisdictions demanded that boards of directors manage companies’ business and set business
policies. However, in publicly held companies, boards performed neither of the functions. In
actual company practice, executives managed companies’ business and set business policies.
Boards in companies such as Penn Central did not perform these functions and could not
prevent the crisis that occurred. Following this observation and the acceptance of the fact that
boards could not be expected to perform the functions that the law demanded, Eisenberg
suggested the monitoring model. The model was invented as a means to change the legal model
of boards so that boards serve a role which is both important to companies and uniquely suited
for performance by the boards, rather than to rigidly apply their functions to the legal model.
Under the monitoring model, management and policy-making are functions of executives.
In contrast, the role of the monitoring board is “to hold the executives accountable for
adequate results” (Eisenberg, 1976). According to the model, what boards of directors
PAGE 1000 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCE jVOL. 19 NO. 5 2019

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT