Subsidies: Some Work, Others Don't

AuthorBenedict J. Clements and Ian Parry
Pages56-57
56 FINANCE & DEVELOPMENT | September 2018
ART: THE NOUN PRO JECT / MA SSUPA KAE WGAHYA
Subsidies: Some Work, Others Don’t
Some government subsidies make sense, but often there are downsides
Benedict J. Clements and Ian Parry
NORWAY EXEMPTS OWNERS
of electric vehicles from
paying highway tolls. In Au stralia, the government
pays part of the wages w hen businesses hire young
people, indigenous Austral ians, or older workers.
Singapore oers tax brea ks to companies that estab-
lish global or regional headqua rters in the country.
All these a re examples of subsidies—scal tools
governments use to encourage economic devel-
opment, help disadvantaged groups, or advance
other national objectives.
Subsidies take many forms. Governments some-
times keep prices articially high, which is the case
with subsidies intended to boost the incomes of
farmers. ey may oer services, such as a uni-
versity education or a subway ride, at below cost.
ey may pay some of the interest on loans used
to nance construction of a road or a power plant.
Or they may grant relief from taxes on certain
products or technologies.
When do subsidies make sense? ey can be a
good policy tool when used to correct so -called
market imperfections; t hat is, when competitive,
private markets fail to del iver socially desirable
outcomes. For example, subsidies can encoura ge
businesses to invest in research and development
that benets not only their rm, but the industr y or
society as well. ey c an also help start-ups survive
an initial period of losse s until they grow large
enough to be protable (although governments
need enough information to determine whether
rms will succ eed when they grow larger).
Impact on inequality
But there are drawbacks. C onsider energy subsidies,
which are often intended to help low-income house-
holds. ese can be a dra in on government resources
if they are avail able to everyone, including those
who are relatively well-o. A targe ted cash transfer
aimed at poor households costs fa r less. Subsidies can
also exacerbate ine quality if they disproportionately
benet those producing or consuming the most. For
example, across Af rica, Asia, Latin America, and
the Middle East, the top 20 percent of households
capture on average seven times a s many of the bene-
ts of energy subsidies as do the bottom 20 perc ent
(Coady, Flamini, and Sears 2015).
Another drawback: sub sidies that do not address
market imperfect ions can distort prices, causing a
misallocat ion of scarce labor and capital that under-
mines growth. Propping up petroleum price s, for
example, may arti cially keep rms aoat in energ y-
intensive sectors and damp investment in a lter-
native energy. Producer subsidies in agriculture,
which increase prices received by fa rmers above
prices for imported food products, also reduce
incentives for improving eciency. In the European
Union, these subsidies averaged 20 percent of
gross farm receipts in 2014–16, according to a
2017 report by the Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development.
Some subsidies can be harm ful, such as those for
fossil fuels. ey a re not only expensive but also at odds
with environmental objectives, such a s reducing deaths
caused by local a ir pollution or meeting commitments
under the 2015 Paris Climate Cha nge Agreement to
BACK TO BASICS

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT