Intellectual Property Rights and International Free Trade - New Jurisprudence of International Exhaustion Doctrine under Traditional Legal System

AuthorChung-Lun Shen
PositionAssociate Professor, Department of Law, National Chengchi University, Taiwan
Pages176-211


 !∀
176
Intellectual Property Rights and International Free Trade:
New Jurisprudence of International Exhaustion Doctrine
under the Traditional Legal System
Chung-Lun Shen
Associate Professor
Department of Law, National Chengchi University, Taiwan
clshen@nccu.edu.tw
Abstract. The interaction between the exhaustion of intellectual property rights and the
parallel importation has been being one of the most controversial issues under international
intellectual property laws. Consequ ently, the main purposes of this article is to assure tha t
intellectual property law—in particular, the exhaustion doctrine—is best fit to deal with the issue
of the conflict between intellectual property rights and international free trade. Meanwhile, this
article is also to determine that the international exhaustion doctrine is the optimal legal model
for the harmonization goal through examining the th eoretical arguments and observing legal
experience in the global community.
© 2012 Chung-Lun Shen .Published b y JICLT. All rights reserved.
I. Introduction
The interaction between the exhaustion of intellectual property rig hts and the parallel importation has been one
of the most controversial issues under international intellectual property laws. This issue arouses the strained
conflicting po sitions in bo th the protection of intellectual pro perty rights and the maintenance of international
free trade. Since each countr y in the global community has faced discrepant political, economic and social
backgrounds, the divergent exhaustion doctrine is preferred around the global community—basically, while the
developing countrie s are dedicated to expanding the scope of the exhaustion doctrine, the developed countries
tend to stick to more protection on intellectual propert y rights. The internationally undecided status in the
adoption of the exhaustion doctrine also led to the fact that the WTO (World Trade Organization) and the
WIPO(World Intellectual property Organization) gave up proposing the uniform exhaus tion doctrine, leaving the
member states absolute discretion in deciding the scope of the exhaust ion doctrine.
Nonetheless, there are two main potential defects in the attitude held by the WTO and the WIPO. One is
reflected in the worry about whether the national decision of the exhaustion doctrine is exactly based on
reconciling the protection of intellectual property rights and the maintenance of international free trade, some
other factors irrelevant to intel lectual property laws being excluded in the decision o f the exhaustion doctrine. If
the exhaustion doctrine is used to achieve the policy goals outside of intellectual property laws, the protection of
intellectual property rights would be excessively developed.
Another concern involves the possibility that some developed countries with strong bargaining power would
force the developing co untries to adopt the exhaustion doctrine favourable to the fulfilment of the specific
economic polic y of the developed countries through bilateral or multilateral trade negotiations. This potential
result would break down the original balance mechanism established by the exhaustion doctrine between the two
conflicting interests of intellectual property rights and international free trad e, and distort international free trade.
In view of the potential defects in the international undecided attitude about the exhaustion doc trine and the
consequential influence, in this author’s view, it is necessary to establish a globally harmonized exhaustion
doctrine in the WTO or WIPO to implicate the optimal interest balance be tween intellectual property rights and


 !∀
177
international free trade. Conseq uently, the main purposes of this article is to assure that intellectual property
law—in particular, the exhaustion doctrine—is the optimal legal approach to deal with the issue of the conflict
between intellectual property rights and international free trade. Meanwhile, this article is also to determine that
the international exhaustion doctrine is the optimal legal model for the harmonizatio n goal by examining the
theoretical arguments and observing legal experience in the global co mmunity.
This article is divided into five sections. T he first section is the introduction for this article. The second
mainly indicates the two co nflicting interests between the protection of intellectual property rights and the
maintenance of inter national free trade that are reflected in the cases of parallel importation. Another core
content of section two (2) is to determine whether intellectual property laws (the exhaustio n doctrine) are best fit
to deal with the issue of parallel importation to balance the interest consideratio n under both intellectual property
rights and international free trade.
Section 3 concentrates on the theoretical and academic d ebates over the application of the international
exhaustion doctrine on the issue of parallel importation. There are two parts in the debates—while one is based
on the policy consideration, the other is according to the economic analysis. Regarding the policy and economic
arguments, this chapter bifurcates the positions into the two groups—one for the international exhaustion
doctrine and the other against the doctrine. Section 4 contains the arguments supporting the international
exhaustion doctrine in section three,. The dissertation indicates, in ter ms of laws and international trade
practices, the weak theoretical basis and misconception about the gist of intellectual proper ty laws on the
arguments against the international exhaustion doctrine. In addition, from the angle of the observation of legal
experience in the global community, it is found that the harmonized international exhaustion doctrine would not
bring about the unbearable im pact in the global community. Consequently, the inter national exhaustion doctrine
is concluded as an optimal legal model. Moreover, this article also p robes into the issues about the application of
the international exhaustion doctrine to determine whether the internatio nal exhaustion doctrine should be
indiscriminately applied to various intellectual property rights, re-importation, and different goods embodied
with intellectual property rights. Section five develops the conclusio n of this article.
2. Intellectual Property Rights and International Free Trade—The Interests Conflicting in
Terms of Parallel Import and the Legal Approach for Resolution
2.1 The Exclusive Rights against Distribution of Goods under Intellectual Property Laws
The exclusive right under inte llectual property rights against the distribution of goods is the focus of the cases of
parallel imports. The distribution right, through le gislation or legal interpretation, under patent law, trademark
law, copyright law, is a potential threat to parallel imports.
2.1.1 Patent Law
The legislative purpose of patent law is mainly to provide inventors with a limited monopoly and sufficient
incentives to engage in cre ating or inventing new technologies benefiting people around the country.
1
Generally
speaking, the protection o f patent law, in terms of an international comparative perspective, reaches out to
infringement during manufacture and infringement after manufacture.
2
Infringement during manufacture is the
1
Clause 8 of Section 8, Article I of the Constitution of the United States: “To promote the Progress of Science and useful
arts, by s ecuring for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and
Discoveries;” ; See a lso Martin J. Adelman et al., Cases and Materials on Patent Law § 1.5[a][1] (3d ed. 2009) [ hereinafter
M
ARTIN
J.
A
DELMAN ET AL
.,
P
ATENT
L
AW
]; F.
S
COTT
K
IEFF ET AL
.,
P
RINCIPLE OF
P
ATENT
L
AW
-C
ASES AND M ATERIALS
66-67
(4
th
ed. 2008) [ hereinafter
F.
S
COTT
K
IEFF ET AL
.,
P
ATENT
L
AW
]; R
OBERT
P. M
ERGES ET AL
., I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
IN THE
N
EW
T
ECHNOLOGICAL
A
GE
23 (2d ed. 2000) [ hereinafter
M
ERGES ET AL
.,
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
]; W.R. C
ORNISH
,
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
: P
ATENTS
, C
OPYRIGHTS
, T
RADE
M
ARKS
AND
A
LLIED
R
IGHTS
¶¶ 3-38 to -48 (5 th ed. 2003)
[hereinafter
C
ORNISH
,
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
].
2
See C
ORNISH
,
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
¶¶
6-09
to -20.


 !∀
178
illegal copy or imitation of the patented products or the patented inventio n process.
3
Infringement a fter
manufacture occurs when patented products or products manufactured under a patented invention process,
regardless of the illegal copies or authorized ones, are sold, offered to sell, or imported without patentee’s
consent.
4
From the angle of infringement after manufacture, patent la w creates an exclusive right related to the
marketing of the patented products or the pro ducts under patented process, that is, the patentee has an exclusive
right to control the distribution of goods in the local market, even blocking goods from c oming into the local
market from the foreign countries.
2.1.2. Trademark Law
Traditionally, trademark law is used to protect the first user of trademark in commerce from likelihood o f
confusion of the two marks occurring when the subsequent users employ the same or similar trademark.
5
The
protection reflects consideratio n of two interests —consumer’s interest and trademark owner’s interest.
6
On
consumer’s interest, the traditional protection of trademark serves a function of source indicator, assisting
consumers in finding the accurate commercial commodities by the evaluation of trademark in mind under a low
search cost.
7
The consideration of trademark owner’s interest drives a guarantee of product q uality because
trademark law awards t he trademark owner sufficient incentive to maintain or improve the qualities of the
commodities.
8
Lately, trademark protection has evolved to cover the economic value of a trademark being formed through
the trademark owner’s investment in developing co mmodities and creating goodwill.
9
As a result, the dilution of
the reputed trademark becomes a kind of infringement under trademark la w.
10
3
See 35 U.S.C. § 271( a) (2003) (“Except as otherwise provided in this title, whoever without authority makes, uses... any
patented invention, within the United States…during the term of the Patent therefor, infringes the patent.”); See also Article
25 of Convention for the European Patent for the Common Market, 1976 Q.J. (L401) 1-28 [hereinafter the Propo sed
Community Patent Convention] (The convention is proposed for establishment of community patent and harmonization of
patent law within the European Econ omic Community and amended in 1989, but never ratified by all Member States. See
Hanns Ullrich, Patent Protection in Europe: Integrating Europe into the Community or the Community into Europe?, 8 E
UR
.
L
.
J
.
437-38 (2002).); Article 7 of Proposal for a Council Regulation on the Community Patent, Council document 7119/04, 8
March 2004[hereinafter Compact 2004]; Article 28 of Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights,
Apr. 15, 1994, Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization [hereinafter the WTO Agreement], Annex
1C, L
EGAL
I
NSTRUMENTS
—R
ESULTS O F THE
U
RUGUAY
R
OUND
vol. 31, 33 I.L.M. 81 (1994) [hereinafter the TRIPS
Agreement].
4
See 35 U.S.C. § 271(a) (2003) (“Except as otherwise provided in this title, whoever without authority…offers to sell, or
sells any patented invention, within the United States or imports into the United States any patented invention during the term
of the patented therefore, infringes the patent.”); See also Article25 of the Proposed Community Patent Convention; Article
28 of the TRIPS Agreement.
5
See M
ERGES ET AL
.,
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
,
supra note 1, at 559; Polaroid Co rp. v. Polarad Elecs. Corp., 287 F.2d 492,
495 (2d Cir. 1961); AMF v. Sleekcraft Boats, 599 F.2d 341, 346 (9th Cir. 1979).
6
See T
IMOTHY
H.
H
IEBERT
,
P
ARALLEL
I
MPORTATION IN
U.S.
T
RADEMARK
L
AW
21-24
(1994)
[hereinafter H
IEBERT
,
P
ARALLEL
I
MPORTATION
].
7
See J
EREMY
P
HILLIPS
, T
RADE
M
ARK
L
AW
¶¶
2.24
to .29 (2003); C
ORNISH
,
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
, supra note
1,
15-24.
See also W
ILLIAM
M.
L
ANDES
&
R
ICHARD
A.
P
OSNER
,
T
HE
E
CONOMIC
S
TRUCTURE OF
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
L
AW
166-68
(2003)
[hereinafter L
ANDES
&
P
OSNER
,
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
L
AW
]
(“The benefits of trademarks in lowering consumer
search costs presuppose legal protection….”)
8
See H
IEBERT
,
P
ARALLEL
I
MPORTATION
,
supra note 6, at 3-6.
9
The dilution theory of trademark is introduced to the United States b y Professor Frank I. Schechter through his classic
article “The Rational Basis of Trademark Protection”. See Frank I. Schechter, The Rational Basis of Trademark Protection,
40 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
.813 (1927). Regarding the development of the dilution theory under trademark law, see T
ONY
M
ARTINO
,
T
RADEMARK
D
ILUTION
(1996).
10
See 15 U.S.C. § 1125(c) (1999); Article 5(2) of First Council Directive 89/104/EEC of 21 December 1988 to approximate
the laws of the Members States Relating to Trade Marks, 1989 Q.J. (L040) 1-7 [hereinafter E.C. Trademark Directive];
Moseley v. V Secret Catalogue, Inc., 537 U.S . 418 (2003); Nabisco, Inc. v. PF Brands, Inc., 191 F.3d 2 08 (2d Cir. 1999);
Ringling Bros.-Barnum & Bailey Combined
Shows, Inc. v. Utah Div. of Tr avel Dev., 170 F.3d 449 (4th Cir. 1999);
Wagamama Ltd. v. City Cenre Restaurant, [1995] F.S.R. 713 (U.K. Case); Baywatch Prod. Co. Ltd. v. Home
Video Channel, [1997] F.S.R. 22.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT