Influence of a Wife's Working Status on Her Husband's Accumulation of Human Capital

AuthorYukichi Mano,Eiji Yamamura
Date01 December 2013
Published date01 December 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/asej.12017
Influence of a Wife’s Working Status on Her
Husband’s Accumulation of Human Capital*
Yukichi Mano and Eiji Yamamura
Received 9 November 2011; accepted 5 March 2013
Japanese household-level data consisting of husband’s earnings, wife’s working
status and their schooling levels are used to test three hypotheses, with particular
consideration given to the time-consuming process of human capital accumulation
within marriages. The empirical results supports the following hypotheses: (i) a
non-working wife’s schooling has a greater positive effect on her husband’s earn-
ings than a working wife’s schooling; and (ii) the effect of a non-working wife’s
schooling increases with the length of marriage, whereas the effect of a working
wife’s schooling does not change over the course of marriage.
Keywords: human capital, schooling, health, working status, cross-productivity
effect, assortative mating effect.
JEL classification codes: I12, I21, J12, J22, J24.
doi: 10.1111/asej.12017
I. Introduction
Although human capital accumulation often requires costly investment in formal
education and working experience (e.g. Becker, 1964; Heckman and Polachek,
1974; Mincer, 1974; Ashenfelter and Krueger, 1994; Behrman et al., 1994; Card,
1999), it also results from interaction with one’s environment. In fact, economic
outcomes, such as an individual’s earnings, are often associated with family
and community backgrounds (e.g. Behrman and Wolfe, 1984; Boulier and
Rosenzweig, 1984; Hauser and Sewell, 1986; Corcoran, 1992). For example, a
person’s earnings are positively associated with their parents’ schooling (e.g.
Heckman and Hotz 1986; Lam and Shoeni, 1993, 1994; Behrman et al. 1999),
and learning from neighbors can help a person increase both productivity and
income (Foster and Rosenzweig 1995; Conley and Udry, 2010).
It is thus natural to expect that such human capital accumulation through social
interaction also occurs between a husband and wife. Benham (1974) was the first
to argue that an educated wife improves her husband’s productivity and, there-
fore, increases his earnings. This is the so called cross-productivity effect within
marriage (see also Scully, 1979; Kenny, 1983; Wong, 1986; Lam and Shoeni,
1993; Jepsen, 2005; Lefgren and McIntyre, 2006; Mano and Yamamura, 2011;
*Mano (correspondence author): Hitotsubashi University, 2-1 Naka, Kunitachi-shi, Tokyo 186-
8601, Japan. Email: yukichi.mano@gmail.com. Yamamura: Department of Economics, Seinan
Gakuin University, 6-2-92 Nishijin, Sawara-ku, Fukuoka 815-0075, Japan.
bs_bs_banner
Asian Economic Journal 2013, Vol. 27 No. 4, 323–339 323
© 2013 The Authors
Asian Economic Journal © 2013 East Asian Economic Association and Wiley Publishing Asia Pty Ltd
Yamamura and Mano, 2012). This effect is distinct from the assortative-mating
effect; that is, educated women tend to be matched in marriage with high-ability
men who have high earnings (Welch, 1974; Liu and Zhang, 1999).1As is evident
from the literature, disentangling the cross-productivity effect from the
assortative-mating effect has been a major challenge. Using data for twins to
control for the unobserved mating effect, Huang et al. (2009) find that cross-
productivity is significant in explaining the patterns of earnings among Chinese
households. It is not clear whether the finding of Huang et al. is readily general-
izable beyond the Chinese context. More importantly, the mechanism of the
cross-productivity effect has yet to be clarified. The present paper attempts to
identify more clearly the mechanism underlying the cross-productivity effects by
investigating recent Japanese household data relating to the earnings, human
capital characteristics and working status of husbands and wives.
It is well established that both the quantity and the quality of education
improve a person’s productivity and earnings (Welch, 1966; Johnson and
Stafford, 1973; Behrman and Birdsall, 1983; Card and Krueger, 1992). Quantity
of education is often measured by the number of years of schooling. Quality of
schooling could be measured according to the educational level of teachers.
Therefore, it should be possible to use an analogous framework to analyze the
cross-productivity effect where a wife improves her husband’s productivity and
earnings. The ‘quality’ may in this case be measured by a wife’s schooling; the
‘quantity’ may be measured by the number of years of marriage and by the
time the wife spends dedicated to improving her husband’s knowledge and
well-being.2
We found that the positive effect of a non-working wife’s education on her
husband’s earnings is greater than that of a working wife’s. Moreover, the effect
of a wife’s schooling increases with the length of marriage only in the case of a
non-working wife, who has more time to devote to improving her husband’s
human capital than a working wife. We also found evidence that a wife’s school-
ing is positively associated with at least one particular aspect of her husband’s
human capital: health. In the analysis below, we will use a switching regression
model to address a possible endogeneity bias arising from a wife’s labor supply
decision.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we will
explain our conceptual framework and set out our estimation strategy. Section III
describes the dataset. Section IV presents the estimation results. Section V
concludes.
1 It is widely observed that a wife’s human capital positively influences her husband’s earnings (e.g.
in Israel (Neuman and Ziderman, 1992), Iran (Scully, 1979), the Philippines (Boulier and Rosenzweig,
1984), Malaysia (Amin and Jepsen, 2005) and Brazil (Lam and Shoeni, 1993, 1994)).
2 Using US census data from 1960 to 2000, Jepsen (2005) finds that a husband’s earnings increase
with his wife’s education. However, the magnitude of the effect declines over cohorts, and Jepsen
conjectures that the rapid increase in a wife’s labor supply reduces her time to improve her husband’s
productivity.
ASIAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL 324
© 2013 The Authors
Asian Economic Journal © 2013 East Asian Economic Association and Wiley Publishing Asia Pty Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT