‘If the Facts Don't Fit the Theory … ’: The Security Design Puzzle in Venture Finance

Published date01 October 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijmr.12032
Date01 October 2014
AuthorSimona Zambelli
‘If the Facts Don’t Fit the Theory . . . ’:
The Security Design Puzzle in
Venture Finance
Simona Zambelli
Department of Management, Piazzale della Vittoria, 15, 47100 Forlì, Italy
Corresponding author email: simona.zambelli@unibo.it
When confronting theory with evidence, divergent results surface with reference to the
optimal securities that should be adopted in venture capital (VC) finance. The vast majority
of the theoretical models on VC consistently predict that convertible securities, especiallyin
the form of convertible preferred stocks, represent the optimal form of finance. While the
theoretical literature seems to be supported by empirical studies in the US, the evidence
outside the US shows the opposite results. Puzzling patterns emerge, especially when
comparing the evidence from the US, Canada and Europe, and an intensive academic debate
is under way. The evidence becomes even more challenging when considering the contrast-
ing financing behaviour of US venture capitalists (VCs) investing in Canada. It has been
documented that US VCs investing in Canada adopt a wide range of securities other than
convertible stocks. If convertible securities truly represent the optimal form of VC finance,
why would US VCs use different types of securities when investing in Canada? At present,
researchers are still arguing about which factors would have the most significant impact on
explaining the different financing behaviour of VCs around the world. The purpose of this
paper is to shed some light on the ongoing international debate on the optimal security
design and contracting behaviour in venture finance. With this review, the authors intend to
contribute to the VC literature by identifying current trends, explanations and determinants
underlying the puzzling empirical evidence on the financing structure adopted by VCs
around the world.
Introduction
‘If the facts don’t fit the theory, change the facts.’
Albert Einstein
The vast majority of theoretical models on venture
capital (VC) consistently predict that convertible
securities, especially in the form of convertible pre-
ferred stocks, represent the optimal form of finance
that should be adopted in VC.1When comparing the
economic theory with the empirical evidence
from the US (e.g. Bengtsson 2012), Europe (e.g.
Cumming 2008; Hartmann-Wendels et al. 2011;
Schwienbacher 2008) and Canada (e.g. Cumming
2012; Cumming 2005a,b,c), inconsistencies emerge.
While the theoretical literature seems supported by
empirical studies in the US, the evidence outside the
US is quite challenging. Inconsistent patterns
surface, especially when considering the contrasting
The author owes special thanks to the Government of
Canada. This study was undertaken with the financial
support of the Foreign Affairs and International Trade
Canada/avec l’appui d’Affaires étrangères et Commerce
international du Canada. The author would also like to
thank the associate editor (Kathryn Haynes) and three
anonymous referees of this Journal for valuable comments
and helpful suggestions, as well as the Fondazione Cariplo
(Milan) for additional financial support.
1For recent overviews of theoretical models on the optimal
security design in VC, see Hirsch and Walz(2013); Andrieu
(2012); Utset (2013); Bienz and Hirsch (2012); Bienz and
Walz (2010).
bs_bs_banner
International Journal of Management Reviews, Vol. 16, 500–520 (2014)
DOI: 10.1111/ijmr.12032
© 2014 British Academy of Management and JohnWiley & Sons Ltd. Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd,9600 Garsington
Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA
financing behaviour of US venture capitalists (VCs)
investing in Canada (e.g. Cumming 2012). Why do
US VCs behave differently when financing Canadian
firms? The economic literature has provided various
explanations for this financing puzzle, but without
converging towards a conclusive position.
The main purpose of this paper is to critically
assess how VC organizations finance their invest-
ments, with the hope of putting together the pieces of
the puzzle highlighted above and shedding some
light on the ongoing international debate surround-
ing the security design in venture finance. For the
purpose of this paper, the term ‘venture capital’ is
adopted with a broad connotation, consistent with
the definition commonly employed in Europe and
other countries such as Canada, and refers to any
equity investments in non-quoted firms. From this
perspective, VC includes start-up and early-stage
investments towards new firms, and mid- and late-
stage investments towards existing and mature firms
(e.g. Cumming and Johan 2008b; Wright et al.
2005).2Venturecapitalists raise money from external
investors (mainly from banks, insurance companies,
pension funds and corporations) and provide capital
to private firms in order to support their development
and innovation process (Bertoni and Tykvova 2012).
Venture capitalists provide both capital and manage-
rial assistance to their investee companies and
usually retain various control rights over their port-
folio companies in order to shape their governance
and maximize their value added (e.g. Cumming
2008; Cumming and Walz 2010; Cumming et al.
2010; Hirsch and Walz 2013; Nielsen 2008). Active
involvement byVCs has proved to be one of the most
effective strategies for adding value to their portfolio
companies (e.g. Chemmanur et al. 2010; Cumming
and Johan 2013; Cumming and Zambelli 2013;
Cumming et al. 2004, 2005; Suchard 2009).
The types of securities that are selected by VCs
play a crucial role in the success of the venture (see
Cumming 2007). For example, some securities may
offer a higher downside risk protection or higher
control rights to VCs to minimize potential losses.
Other types of securities (e.g. convertible securities)
may offer stronger incentives to entrepreneurs and
minimize their opportunistic actions.
Regarding the use of convertible securities in VC,
the empirical and theoretical studies are disjointed.
On the one hand, the empirical studies in the US
highlight that convertible securities, especially in the
form of convertible preferred stocks, are the most
commonly used form of VC finance (e.g. Bengtsson
2012; Gompers 1997; Sahlman 1988, 1990). This
evidence is in line with the vast majority of theoreti-
cal models on VC contracting behaviour(e.g. Admati
and Pfleiderer 1994; Berglöf 1994; Casamatta 2003;
Cornelli and Yosha 2003; Hellmann 2006; Ozerturk
2008; Repullo and Suarez 2004; Schmidt 2003). On
the other hand, the empirical evidence from Canada
shows that convertible securities do not represent the
most frequently used financial instrument in VC (e.g.
Cumming 2001; 2002; 2006; 2007; 2008; Cumming
and Walz 2010; Cumming et al. 2010).3
The inconsistencies resulting from the empirical
studies around the world challenge the predominant
theoretical models on the optimal financing behav-
iour in VC and raise various questions: Why do VCs
in Canada use forms of finance other than convertible
preferred stocks? Is this evidence explainable by a
lower level of sophistication ofVCs in Canada com-
pared with US VCs, as Kaplan et al. (2007) argued?
How doVCs outside the US and Canada finance their
investee firms? According to Gilson and Schizer
(2003), tax regulation biases the security choice in
the US towards the selection of convertibleprefer red
securities. Consistent with this view are the data
reported in Cumming (2005a). But is the tax policy
2Note that, in the international literature there is no unique
definition of VC. Overlaps and differences in the definitions
of VC and private equity (PE) emerge, depending on the
geographical context. Sometimes, especially in Europe, VC
is adopted with a broad connotation (e.g. Krohmer et al.
2009; Wright et al. 2005) as a synonym of PE. Other times,
especially in Anglo-Saxon contexts, the term VC is used as
a subsample of the entire industry (PE) to identify the early-
stage and expansion financing (e.g. Metrick and Yasuda
2010, 2011a,b; Tykvova and Schertler 2008). Inconsisten-
cies emerge, especially with the term PE (see Appendix S1,
available in the online version of the Journal). In some
European countries, PE involves the equity financing of
existing firms and includes expansion and late-stage financ-
ing, turnaround, and buyouts (e.g. Cumming and Zambelli
2010). In other contexts, PE is used for buyouts only (e.g.
Acharya et al. 2011; Achleitner et al. 2010; Wright et al.
2009). Since buyouts are structured in a different way rela-
tive to early and expansion investments, papers focusing
only on buyouts are excluded from the survey onVC financ-
ing behaviour. For overviews of buyouts, see Zambelli
(2010); Jensen (2007). For overviews of VC activity, see
Metrick and Yasuda (2011b); Wood and Wright (2009);
Schwienbacher (2008); De Clercq et al. (2006); Fried and
Hisrich (1994); Sahlman (1990).
3Similarly, the evidencefrom Europe shows that convertible
stocks are not used as frequently as in the US VC
market (e.g. Cumming 2008; Cumming and Walz 2010;
Schwienbacher 2008).
Security Design Puzzle in Venture Finance 501
© 2014 British Academy of Management and John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT