How does labour share respond to risk? Theory and evidence from the Chinese industrial sector

Published date01 June 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ilr.12111
Date01 June 2020
Copyright © The authors 2020
Journal compilation © International Labour Organization 2020
*National Academy of Development and Strategy, Renmin University of China, email: zou_
jingxian@163.com. **Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University, email: hnshgj@126.com (correspond-
ing author). ***Development Research Centre of the State Council, email: js@drc.gov.cn. The au-
thors would like to thank two anonymous referees for their comments. This study was supported
by the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities and the Research Funds of
Renmin University of China (grant No. 19XNB011).
Responsibility for opinions expressed in signed articles rests solely with their authors, and
publication does not constitute an endorsement by the ILO.
International Labour Review, Vol. 159 (2020), No. 2
How does labour share
respond to risk?
Theory and evidence from
the Chinese industrial sector
Jingxian ZOU,* Guangjun SHEN ** and Shen JIA***
Abstract. This study discusses the role of rm risk in the declining labour share
in China. Based on the model developed by Holmström and Milgrom (1987), the
authors demonstrate that lower rm risk can motivate workers to work harder,
leading to higher output per worker and average wage. However, increased output
will lower the labour share. Using data from the Chinese Industrial Enterprises
Database for the period 1998–2007 and the World Bank’s Investment Climate
Survey 2005 , empirical evidence supports this hypothesis and performs robustly
across various model specications and proxies for rm risk, indicating a positive
correlation between labour share and rm risk.
Keywords: labour share, rm risk, contract theory, industrial sector, China.
1. Introduction
The distribution of national income between capital and labour has always been
of interest to economists and policy-makers. Since the “Kaldor Facts” were rst
put forward (Kaldor, 1957), it has long been claimed that, according to neoclas-
sical economics, the share of national income going to factors of production
should remain constant. However, this claim has been challenged by empirical
evidence documenting drastic changes in labour income share. This evidence
points to a signicant decline in the labour share of developed countries since
the early 1980s, especially in continental European countries (Blanchard, 19 97;
Harrison, 2005; Guscina, 2 006). Although not as pronounced as in Europe, a dis-
cernible downward trend has also been observed in the United States. Indeed,
as argued by Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014), this decline in labour share
has become a global trend.
International Labour Review
260
The literature has furthermore noted the appearance of a similar pattern
in China, where there has been a signicant decline in labour share from the
middle of the 1990s (Bai and Qian, 2 010; Luo and Zhang, 2010). Against the
background of “New Normal Economics”, China is encouraged to boost domes-
tic savings and consumption, rebalance the structure of the external and in-
ternal economy, and change the growth model from the previous factor-driven
model to a new model driven by human capital and innovation. All these tar-
gets depend on the improvement of the population’s income and can hardly be
achieved if the labour share keeps declining.
Important as the study of labour share change is, no agreement has been
reached on the mechanism behind it. The main explanations given for China’s
declining labour share can be roughly divided into four categories: (1) factor-
biased technological progress; (2) structural change; (3) reforms including pri-
vatization, restructuring of state-owned enterprises and ownership reforms; and
(4) globalization, especially in the form of foreign direct investment (FDI).
First, from the perspective of technology, if technological change is labour-
augmenting, then a balanced growth model would imply a constant labour share
(Acemoglu, 2003; Bentolila and Saint-Paul, 20 03). However, this contrasts with
the pattern observed in China. Huang and Xu (2009) argue that it was labour-
saving technological progress that led to the decline of labour share in China
after 1995. Second, in terms of structural change, the relative growth of the ser-
vice sector compared with the agricultural sector is perceived as one of the two
driving forces behind the decline in the labour share over the last three decades
(Bai and Qian, 2010). Third, a series of economic reforms have had an inu-
ential impact on the labour market. Yang (1999) lists various institutional fac-
tors in China that resulted in labour income change, including labour mobility
restrictions, welfare systems and nancial policies oering ination subsidies
and investment credits to the urban sector. Moreover, by investigating the dis-
tortions in product and factor markets, Bai and Qian (2010) ascribe the labour
share decline within the manufacturing sector after 1998 to the restructuring of
state-owned enterprises and to expanded monopoly power. Lastly, international
studies on labour share also identify globalization as having a major role. For
instance, Harrison (20 05) provides evidence of its eect on labour share in de-
veloped countries. In the case of China, Luo and Zhang (2010) point to the nega-
tive inuence of FDI on labour share due to regional competition, which weak-
ens the labour force’s bargaining power and thus reduces labour income share.
In general, the abovementioned explanations for change in labour share
take a fundamentally macroeconomic approach. In contrast, in this article we
focus on microeconomic dimensions, restricting our attention to change at rm
level within the industrial sector.
We restrict our focus to the secondary sector on account of its importance
and representativeness. This sector has long been, and will long continue to be
important for the overall economy. During our sample period (1998–2007 ), it
was consistently the largest sector in terms of value added, accounting for more
than 45 per cent of the total most years (20 02 being the only exception). More re-
cently, although the industrial sector was overtaken in size by the service sector
in 2013, its share remains above 4 2 per cent and still accounts for a large portion

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT