Estimating currency misalignment using the Penn effect: It is not as simple as it looks

AuthorMenzie Chinn,Xin Nong,Yin‐Wong Cheung
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/infi.12113
Published date01 December 2017
Date01 December 2017
DOI: 10.1111/infi.12113
ORIGINAL MANUSCRIPT
Estimating currency misalignment using the Penn
effect: It is not as simple as it looks
Yin-Wong Cheung
1
|
Menzie Chinn
2
|
Xin Nong
3
1
Department of Economics and
Finance, City University of Hong Kong,
Hong Kong
2
Department of Economics, Robert M.
La Follette School of Public Affairs,
University of Wisconsin, Madison,
Wisconsin
3
Department of Government, University
of Texas at Austin, Austin, Texas
Correspondence
Menzie Chinn, Department of
Economics, Robert M. La Follette School
of Public Affairs, University of
Wisconsin, Madison, WI.
Email: mchinn@lafollette.wisc.edu
Abstract
We investigate the robustness of the Penn effectthe
finding that the price level is higher in countries with a
higher per capita incomeover different samples, mea-
sures, and specifications. Testing for the Penn effect has
been hampered by the imprecision of the price measures, so
that use of different versions of the data set can lead to
substantially different results. We find that the price level-
income elasticity is fairly consistently estimated across data
sets. However, there is some evidence that the relationship
is non-linear. For developed economies, the quadratic
term implies an inverted U-shap ed relationship. Devel-
oping economies, on the other han d, display a U-shaped
relationship. Estimates of misalignment diff er, depending
on the choice of specification an d data sets. It appears that
the Renminbi (RMB) was fairly valued by 2011. In
contrast, the RMB's value was un dervalued in 2005, and
overvalued in 2014.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The issue of currency misalignment is a perennial one. As long as countries strive to reallocate
aggregate demand in their own favour, disputes will arise regarding the degree to which currency
values are fair. The problem, of course, is what constitutes such a fair value; each different model
yields its own valuation.
One key strand of methodologies involves the comparison of price levels as a means of inferring the
proper currency value. Absolute purchasing power parity (PPP) is one particularly simple, and
particularly inappropriate, price criterion. After all, the proposition that similar bundles of goods
should be equally priced when denominated in a common currency is one of the most frequently
violated ones.
222
|
© 2017 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/infi International Finance. 2017;20:222242.
A more commonly used criterion is the Penn effect. One of the most well-documented empirical
regularities in the international finance literaturethe finding that the price level is higher in countries
with a higher per capita incomeis consistent with a variety of theoretical frameworks, including a
BalassaSamuelson mechanism, and demand side forces including a preference for non-tradable goods
at higher incomes (i.e. non-homotheticity).
1
In this paper, we seek to document whether indeed the Penn effect is as robust as is typically
conceived, over different samples, measures, and specifications. Testing for the Penn effect has been
hampered by the imprecision with which the price data are measured. This means that new versions of
the data set can lead to substantially different results.
2
Further, some recent work has suggested the
presence of a non-linear Penn effect, namely a quadratic link between income and real exchange rate.
To anticipate our results, we find that the elasticity of the relative price level to per capita income is
fairly consistently estimated, across data sets. However, there is some evidence that the relationship is
non-linear; a statistically significant quadratic term, implying a U-shaped relationship, is estimated.
The nature of the non-linearity displayed by developed and developing economies differs. For
developed economies, the quadratic term implies an inverted U-shaped relationship between real
exchange rate and income. Developing economies, on the other hand, display a U-shaped relationship.
Additional analyses suggest that the non-linearity is likely driven by variation across countries rather
than by variation within a country. The estimated quadratic term is robust to the addition of select
economic covariates in the regressions.
In the case of China, the inclusion of a significant quadratic term, unsurprisingly, has implications
for the magnitude of the estimated degree of misalignment, particularly when the full country sample is
used in determining the exchange rate norm. Estimates of misalignment for other currencies will differ
as well, to varying degrees, depending on the choice of linear versus quadratic specification. The
choice of data sets also has a material impact on the estimates.
In terms of the Chinese currency, it appears that the Renminbi (RMB) was fairly valued by 2011. In
contrast, the RMB's value was undervalued in 2005, and overvalued in 2014 if one uses a one standard
error threshold; not so if one uses a two standard error convention. Hence, depending on one's
perspective regarding the proper significance level to apply to policy questions, the deviation was
statistically significant (Frankel, 2006) or not (Cheung, Chinn, & Fujii, 2007).
Looking forward, according to our estimates, as long as Chinese per capita growth exceeds that of
the United States, then the long-run equilibrium value of the RMB will continue to rise. The pace of
increase is about 0.25 for each 1% increase in relative per capita income, holding constant other factors
such as financial openness and levels of corruption.
2
|
BACKGROUND
At the heart of the debate over the right way of determining the appropriate exchange rate level are
contrasting ideas of what constitutes an equilibrium exchange rate, what time frame the equilibrium
condition pertains to, and, not least, what econometric method to implement.
Most of the extant studies fall into some familiar categories, either relying upon some form of
relative PPP or cost competitiveness calculation, the modelling of deviations from absolute PPP,
3
a
composite model incorporating several channels of effects (sometimes called behavioural equilibrium
exchange rate models), or flow equilibrium models. These alternative approaches are reviewed in, for
example, Cheung et al. (2007), and Cheung, Chinn, and Fujii (2010a).
In this study, we appeal to a simple, and apparently robust, relationship between the real exchange
rate and per capita income. We then elaborate the analysis by stratifying the data by level of income,
CHEUNG ET AL.
|
223

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT