Dealing with informational asymmetries under the proposed CESL and CISG

Date07 September 2012
DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1108/14770021211267388
Published date07 September 2012
Pages281-299
AuthorChristian Twigg‐Flesner
Subject MatterEconomics
Dealing with informational
asymmetries under the proposed
CESL and CISG
Christian Twigg-Flesner
Law School, University of Hull, Hull, UK
Abstract
Purpose – This paper aims to explore the way in which informational asymmetries between the two
parties to a contract for the sale of goods are dealt with under two legal regimes designed for
transnational sales contracts: the UN Convention on the International Sale of Goods (CISG) and the
proposed Common European Sales Law (CESL).
Design/methodology/approach Having considered the different types of informational
asymmetry that can exist in a contract of sale, the paper undertakes a doctrinal legal analysis of
the relevant provisions f‌irst in the CESL and then the CISG to identify what, if anything, has been done
to deal with informational asymmetries. The paper primarily exposes and analyses these rules and
compares the approaches taken under both legal regimes.
Findings – The CESL has a more detailed set of rules which address informational asymmetries.
This might be because the genesis and context of the CESL (being limited to the EU) might make it
easier to agree on more extensive rules. However, the CESL has not yet been adopted.
Practical implications – A seller in a contract of sale governed by CESL will be subject to more
detailed (and onerous) requirements when it comes to the disclosure of information.
Originality/value – This is a f‌irst attempt to compare the treatment of informational asymmetries
under the CISG and CESL, and will be of interest to scholars of both transnational and EU private law.
Keywords Common EuropeanSales Law (CESL),
Conventionon Contracts for the InternationalSale of Goods (CISG), European Unioncross-borders sales,
Consumer protection,Pre-contractual information,Information asymmetry, Information
Paper type Research paper
Introduction
The focus of this article is on the role of informational asymmetries between sellers
and buyers of goods, and the various provisions in the UN Convention on Contracts
for the International Sale of Goods 1980 (CISG) and the proposed Common European
Sales Law (CESL)[1] that deal with such asymmetries. The CISG was adopted in
1980 and is concerned with certain aspects of international sale of goods contracts
(contracts between parties whose places of business are in different states[2]).
It primarily deals with the formation of contracts and the respective duties of the seller
and buyer, as well as the associated remedies for breach of those duties. The focus of the
convention is on commercial contracts; consumer contracts are generally excluded from
the scope of the CISG[3].
The CESL marks the culmination of a project which has been on-going for over
a decade. In 2001, the European Commission launched a consultation exercise on the
need for action by the European Union (EU) in the f‌ield of contract law (Common Market
Law Review, 2002; Twigg-Flesner, 2008)[4]. This eventually resulted in the Draft
Common Frame of Reference (DCFR) (von Bar et al., 2009), which was produced
The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at
www.emeraldinsight.com/1477-0024.htm
Informational
asymmetries
281
Journal of International Trade Law
and Policy
Vol. 11 No. 3, 2012
pp. 281-299
qEmerald Group Publishing Limited
1477-0024
DOI 10.1108/14770021211267388
by a network of European legal scholars. The DCFR is a detailed blueprint for legislation
on most aspects of private law. However, as the original focus of the project was
on contract law, a further exercise was undertaken by a group of experts to prepare
a Feasibility Study on EU Contract Law (2010), which then became the basis for
the proposed CESL now under discussion. The CESL is a two-part measure: f‌irst, there is
the so-called “chapeau” part which contains the provisions commonly found in EU
legislation (recitals, def‌initions, scope of application). This part does not contain the
substantive rules on the sale of goods. The second part of the CESL, found in Annex I to
the Regulation, provides the substantive rules. Unlike the CISG, CESL is designed to
apply to contracts between commercial sellers (traders) and consumers (B2C), as well as
commercial transactions between a large business and a small to medium-sized
enterprise (SME)[5]. As such, CESL focuses on different types of contracts (B2 C and
B2SME) with the underlying assumption that one of the parties in both types of
contracts is in a weaker bargaining position than the business or the larger business in
the case of SMEs. The CISG’s scope of application is not limited by considering the
bargaining strength of the buyer, but instead excludes contracts for certain types of
goods (effectively consumer goods) from its scope, with the intention of removing
consumer contracts from the ambit its jurisdiction. This variation in the scope of
application might suggest that the treatment of informational asymmetries will vary
noticeably between the two measures. This article will f‌irst explore the notion of
“informational asymmetries”. This will then be followed by an in-depth analysis of the
relevant provisions in the CESL and the CISG.
Informational asymmetries
In this section[6], the notion of informational asymmetry is explored. The focus is on the
relationship between a seller and buyer of goods. It is well-known assumption about
consumer markets that the information about goods (and services) is distributed
unequally to the detriment of the consumer. This may also be true in many business
transactions. This is a long-recognised problem and is the basis of Akerlof’s (1970)
famous “lemons problem”, which postulates that there is a risk when the buyer does not
possess all relevant information that the buyer might purchase poor-quality goods.
The obvious response to this problem is to require the seller to provide as much
information about the goods as possible, but there are a number of reasons why the seller
might not always be willing to reveal relevant information. Indeed, the issue of
informational asymmetry is not as straightforward as it seems because there are
a number of different forms of informational asymmetries. For present purposes, there
are four types of circumstances:
(1) The seller has information about the goods which the buyer does not have
(“seller-biased asymmetry”).
(2) The buyer has information about the goods which the seller does not have. For
example, the buyer may be aware of particular aspects of the goods through
third-party reports, or through having inspected the goods before deciding to
purchase them (“buyer-biased asymmetry”).
(3) There is information about the goods of which neither the seller nor the buyer
is aware. This is a common situation where there is some sort of latent defect
not apparent on an inspection of the goods (by either party), or when
JITLP
11,3
282

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT