Comment on “The Southeast Asian Economies in the Age of Discontent”

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/aepr.12311
Published date01 July 2020
Date01 July 2020
Comment on The Southeast Asian
Economies in the Age of Discontent
Takatoshi ITO
Columbia University, USA
JEL codes: F02, F60, H12, Z18
Accepted: 28 March 2020
Basri and Hill (2020) ask the question whether the recent global trend of authoritarian
populism has inuenced Southeast Asian countries. Their short answer is No,and
they provide several reasons. If the authoritarian populism in the advanced countries is
triggered by stagnant growth, unemployment, and social discontent with globalization,
then an easy explanation is that the Southeast Asian countries do not have those
socio-economic conditions. In Southeast Asia, growth is still reasonable; unemploy-
ment is not a major problem; and globalization has helped their exports and growth.
The socio-economic backgrounds for the rise of authoritarian regimes in several
advanced and emerging market countries appear to vary from one country to another.
Take the USA for example. The unemployment rate was the highest during the
months following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008. However, the US case does
not exactly t the conventional wisdom of the rise of protectionism (illiberalism) and
populism. The year of the worst economic performance was 2009, when the unem-
ployment rate shot up to 10%. It would not have been surprising if protectionism had
risen then. On the contrary, the G-20 summit meeting reafrmed the value of free
trade. Protectionism under Trump was introduced when the economy was booming,
with a very low unemployment rate. So, why was there no backlash against globaliza-
tion in 2009, but a surge in support for a politician advocating protectionism in 2016?
This is a puzzle (Naoi, forthcoming).
In Basri and Hill (2020), authoritarian and populism are mentioned in one breath.
However, in a true authoritarian state with a one-party system, such as China and
Vietnam, the leader does not have to be a populist since there is no general election. In
a democracy, a candidate for president or prime minister may have to promise many
populist measures to win votes in elections. A closely-contested, democratically elected
authoritarian needs to be a populist, but this is not the case for a true authoritarian in
a non-democratic, one-party system. Where is the line between legitimate political tac-
tics to gain mean voters(in the sense of the mean voter theorem) and populism with
its bad connotation? In some Southeast Asian countries, in the past, a de facto
Correspondence: Takatoshi Ito, School of International and Public Affairs, Columbia Univer-
sity, New York, NY 10027, USA. Email: ti2164@columbia.edu
210 © 2020 Japan Center for Economic Research
doi: 10.1111/aepr.12311 Asian Economic Policy Review (2020) 15, 210211

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT