Bank regulation when both deposit rate control and capital requirements are socially costly

Published date01 June 2018
Date01 June 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12150
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12150
Bank regulation when both deposit rate control and capital
requirements are socially costly
Carsten Krabbe Nielsenand Gerd Weinrich
The bank regulation reforms in the 1980s and 1990s saw deposit rate ceilings being replaced
by minimum capital requirements. However, there seem to be no theoretical studies supporting
these reforms; either the two instruments are considered for all practical purposes equivalent,
or the conclusion is in favor of deposit regulation. In our model there is a real tradeoff between
the two: capital regulation is costly because the opportunity costs of capital are higher than the
return from normal banking activities, while deposit rate ceilings may result in an inefficiently
large number of banks. We show that, depending on the opportunity costs of banking capital
and on the severity of the moral hazard problem they seek to address, each of the two regulatory
instruments may welfare-dominate the other.
Key wor ds banking regulation, moral hazard, deposit rate control, capital requirement, Salop
model
JEL classification D43, D82, G21, G28
Accepted 11 July2016
1 Introduction
Deposit rate ceilings were commonly used in banking regulation until the 1980s when, as part of
a wave of regulatory reforms, they were replaced by capital requirements stipulating that parts of
bank investment funds be supplied by bank owners.1Despite this dramatic change in regulatory
policies, there is, to the best of our knowledge, so far no theoretical model that, contrasting the two
*Department of Economics and Finance, Catholic University of Milan, Milan,Italy.
Department of Mathematical Disciplines, Mathematical Finance and Econometrics, Catholic Universityof Milan, Milan,
Italy.Email: gerd.weinrich@unicatt.it
We are grateful for comments from participants at the following conferences: Italian Economic Association, Annual
Conference 2013; European Economic Association, Annual Meeting 2013; InternationalFinance and Banking Societ y,
Annual Conference2013; Associazione per la Matematica Applicata alle Scienze Economiche e Sociali, Annual Conference
2013; XXII International Conference on Money,Banking and Finance, Rome 2013. Financial support from the Italian
national research project “Local interactions and global dynamics in economics and finance: models and tools”, PRIN-
2009, and from the Catholic University’sresearch projects “Teoriee modelli matematici per le scienze economiche”,UCSC
D.1,and “ The challenges of the crisis: Rethinkingmicroeconomic and macroeconomic policies”,UCSC D3.2, is gratefully
acknowledged.
1All three Basel accords focus on reducingr isk-taking bybanks, and in doing so rely heavily on capital requirements as the
regulatory instrument. The third Basel accord is characterized by a tightening of control and supervision, exemplified by
an increase in capital requirements and a return to more objective standards for defining the riskiness of the individual
bank’s assets.
International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 139–178 © IAET 139
International Journal of Economic Theory
Capital requirements deposit rate ceilings Carsten Krabbe Nielsen and Gerd Weinrich
regulatory regimes, comes out in favor of capital requirements.2The purpose of our contribution is
to formalize a tradeoff between the two regimes, which has at least implicitly been recognized in the
literature, and compare their consequential welfare properties. This is done in a setting where, due
to moral hazard, there is a real need for regulation, since without it banks would take on too much
risk.
Capital requirements are costly because bank capital is costly (this is why bank owners in general
seek to limit their contribution of capital) and these costs are ultimately borne by depositors in
the form of lower deposit rates.3Deposit rate ceilings, on the other hand, depress competition (for
depositors) and increase profits for existing banks. These excess profits, attracting newcomers, lead
to a bloated banking sector, which is also costly to society. This cost, in the form of excess entry,
is widely acknowledged by regulators and is also confirmed by empirical evidence (as we briefly
show later). Nevertheless, no theoretical study seems to have taken it into account in a comparison
of the two regulatory regimes, which is essentially why none have concluded against deposit rate
ceilings.
Since neither type of regulation is without its costs, any comparison of their welfare consequences
should explicitly take them into consideration, as we do here. In particular, taking these costs into
account, it could conceivably be better to not regulate at all. It is therefore important to identify, as
we shall in our analysis, conditions under which either type of regulation leads to higher welfare than
laissez-faire.
Our model, which builds on Hellmann et al. (2000) and Repullo (2004), assumes a continuum of
potential depositors on the unit circle `alaSalop, served by a finite number of imperfectly competitive
banks and covered by deposit insurance. When investing the deposits received, banks may choose
between a risky (“gambling”)asset and a non-r isky (“prudent”)asset, with the former having positive
probability πof a non-positive net return and consequent bankruptcy of the bank, and the latter
having a higher expected return, α, thus being the socially optimal choice. Due to moral hazard prob-
lems (the non-observability of the investment choices of banks), an unregulated banking industry
may end up in a gambling equilibrium (where all banks choose the risky asset) rather than a prudent
equilibrium.4We retain the assumption of Hellmann etal . (2000) and Repullo (2004) that capital
requirements are socially costly since the capital provided by owners has a higher opportunity cost,
denoted ρ, than what it can earn when employed in normal banking activities. The novelty of our
model, which otherwise follows that of Repullo (2004) rather closely, is to allow for an endogenous
determination of the number of banks assuming that these have setup costs C.5Deposit rate ceilings
tend to lead to excess profits (for empirical documentation of this, see, for example, Berger et al.
1995), which in turn leads to the entry of new banks. Like Chiappori et al. (1995), we assume that
banks are free to enter and will do so until profits (including setup costs) are driven down to zero.
Together with the assumption that depositors pay for deposit insurance via taxes, this assumption
2The few theoretical models that do consider both instruments either come out in favor of deposit rate ceilings or take a
neutral stance. We arereferr ing toBhattachar ya (1982), Hellmannet al . (2000), Matutes and Vives (2000) and Repullo
(2004), which we discuss further below.
3Besanko and Thakor (1992, p. 911) were probably the first to observe this: “raising the capital standard is virtually
isomorphic to reimposing Reg Q ceilings on deposit interest rates.
4This formalization of moral hazard in banking goes back to at least Bhattacharya (1982).
5Besanko and Thakor (1992) also studied the effects of varying the number of banks in a Salop-type model. Chiappori
et al. (1995) study the costs, in terms of an increased number of banks, under deposit rate regulation, in a Salop model
with setup costs. However, they do not explicitly considerthe benefits of banking regulation. Gehrig (1995) studies the
welfare consequences of free (and restricted) entry in a model quite different from ours: the model does not consider
moral hazard issues and has only one period.
140 International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 139–178 © IAET
Carsten Krabbe Nielsen and Gerd Weinrich Capital requirements deposit rate ceilings
leads to a simplification of the welfare analysis: to compare the different regulatory regimes we only
need to compare the welfare of the (average) depositor. The possibility of an excess entry of banks at
a cost to society then establishes a tradeoff, as measured by dead-weight costs, between using deposit
rate ceilings and capital requirements as regulatory instruments.
We show that the number of banks in a prudent equilibrium cannot be lower (and may be
higher) in a regulatory regime of deposit rate control than in a regime with capital requirements,
which, in turn, is higher than the optimal number of banks, which then establishes that deposit rate
ceilings carry a social cost. As was observed by Chiappori et al. (1995), the inefficiency associated
with an excessive number of banks may as well be interpreted as an inefficiency due to non-price
competition in the form of product differentiation, that is, of attracting customers by other means
than the deposit rate.6
Our main result finds that when ρis close to α(meaning that capital requirements are not too
socially costly) capital requirements, as a regulatory instrument, dominate deposit rate ceilings.
This is not a surprising conclusion, although the picture is rendered more complicated by the fact
that ρalso plays the role of discount factor and as such influences the franchise value (equal to the
discounted value of future profits) of any bank. On the other hand, we show that, as πincreases,
deposit rate ceilings overtake capital requirements in terms of consumer welfare. We interpret this
as saying that, when the moral hazard problem is severe in the sense of a low probability of default,
making the risky asset more attractive, deposit rate ceilings are an insufficient regulatory tool and
capital requirements are needed.7We provide a numerical example showing that in the case where
deposit rate regulation is welfare optimal, the deposit rate ceiling may or may not be binding in
equilibrium.
1.1 Related literature
The two studies (that we know of) which explicitly compare deposit rate ceilings and capital re-
quirements, Hellmann et al. (2000) and Repullo (2004), both come out in favor of the former as a
measure for preventing moral hazard by banks. The study by Hellmann et al. (2000) finds that while
deposit rate ceilings alone can implement a subset of the (constrained) efficient allocations, capital
requirements always need to be combined with deposit rate control to do so. In fact Hellman et al.
(2000, p. 156) interpret their main proposition as stating that “the current policy regime practiced in
most countries around the world (i.e. using just a capital requirement with no deposit-rate control)
is a Pareto-inferior policy choice.
Repullo (2004) provides an examination of the results of Hellmann et al. (2000) in a general
equilibrium framework where banks maximize profits over an infinite horizon.8The conclusions
of Hellmann et al. (2000) are to a large extent confirmed: deposit rate ceilings are effective (in
eliminating excessive risk-taking by banks) whenever capital requirements are effective, while the
opposite is not the case (Repullo, 2004, p. 175). However, since in the models of Repullo and
(disregarding financial repression) of Hellman et al. capital requirements are socially costly, while
6VanHoose (2010, pp. 76–80) provides a review of the existing literature on non-price competition in the banking sector.
He cites several studies that find that the number of branches or ATMsystems are used by banks to boost the demand for
their products. See also Berger et al. (1995, p. 79) and Hammond and Knott (1988, p. 15).
7Complementing this result, Nielsen (2012) showshow capital control may become ineffective as the riskiness of the risky
asset increases.
8An interesting contribution by Niu (2008) uses the model of Repullo (2004) to study the effects of subordinated debt
requirements assuming the number of banks fixed.
International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 139–178 © IAET 141

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT